Saturday, January 26, 2013

01/26/2013 Rotation, and note on position sizes


Small Portfolio
XLU & IAU
19.69%
Sector
XLU
31.86%
Secular
IAU
7.53%
Large Portfolio
Date
Return
Days
RIMM
7/16/2012
141.93%
194
SEAC
9/25/2012
35.37%
123
CAJ
9/25/2012
7.56%
123
DDAIF
9/25/2012
13.70%
123
CFI
10/31/2012
41.17%
87
RE
11/26/2012
9.86%
61
CGX
12/12/2012
10.59%
45
OKE
12/28/2012
12.48%
29
HTSI
1/14/2013
12.16%
12
STRA
1/22/2013
1.19%
4
S&P
Annualized
6.91%
Small Portfolio
Annualized
11.44%
Sector Model
Annualized
18.14%
Large Portfolio
Annualized
38.21%

 

Rotation: selling STRA; buying NSC

This change is somewhat bullish, since NSC is in the railroad industry, and may indicate a pickup in transportation.

One caveat is the fact that the sector model is in XLU, which has a slight negative bias for the market.  Utilities could be responding to a search for dividend yields as an alternative to bonds.

There’s no way to know.  The market is wildly overbought, but such moves can last a while, and timing is almost a useless exercise for most folks now that Bernanke is pushing yet another round of QE through the end of this year.

My gut tells me to jump and run, but part of this open test is to see the performance of the model in all market environments – which will include a bear market whenever it does come.

So far the model is doing well, but doing well in a bull market is the easy part.  Holding your own against a bear is quite another.  We’ll find out one of these days.

Quick note on position sizes and holding periods.  The model is designed for positions no smaller than 2000 dollars in a taxable account, or 1000 dollars in an IRA.  Those are the EXTREME low ends for a position to withstand trading costs in short term trades.  Any position of lesser value should be held long term – and we have not yet found the endpoint on long positions, so it could be as long as two years a trade.

Tim

 

Friday, January 25, 2013

01/25/2013 AAPL

Apple is all the buzz at the moment.  Is it a buy or a sell?

Fundamentally it would be a buy, but the industry it is in is not cheap enough for my model.

So, it's on watch, but not yet a buy.

Thursday, January 24, 2013

01/24/2013 Conclusion -- and a proposal for both parties


A recent article about the Automate 2013 trade show addressed the question of whether robots are taking our jobs.

The answer was “yes and no.”  That’s been the answer since the dawn of time.  First animals and watermills took our jobs, then automation, and now robotics.  And each time we found better jobs that were easier to do and more rewarding.

But still – the ultimate what-if scenario would be if artificial intelligence ever took over ALL industrial capacity.  How much should we tax corporations that used robots instead of people?

The answer is in my original post on capital gains rates: 35%.

That post assumed no change in investor behavior between 0% and 100% taxation.  Since a robot “behaves” as it’s programmed to behave, the behavior-neutral model applies.  Government revenue peaks at 35%.

The robots don’t produce an end product from nothing, but from raw materials that have to be supplied to the manufacturer.  If the robot has no raw material, the robot itself becomes “unemployed.”  Taxation beyond 35% reduces the amount of raw material purchasing power to the point that the government loses revenue.

So much for robots.  What about humans?

The original form of the “Laffer curve” shows 0% revenues at 0% tax rates, and 0% revenues at 100% tax rates.  The Conservative argument is that people will lose incentive at 100% taxation and stop working.

The Conservatives are wrong.  People work even at 100% tax rates, as we see in Israeli communal Kibbutzim and the old Soviet Union.  In the Israeli Kibbutzim there is peer pressure and the threat of expulsion.  In the old Soviet Union a person who didn’t work didn’t eat – and the gulag was an added incentive.

Here’s the difference: Capitalism rewards work, while Communism punishes idleness.

So, Communism does not have welfare, but Capitalism won’t execute you for being lazy.

Capitalism is the carrot.

Communism is the stick.

Either one will motivate you to work.  The lazy will work harder in Communism and the greedy will work harder in Capitalism… giving Capitalism the edge in total productivity.

But having an edge and cornering the entire market are two different things.  The true Laffer curve does NOT fall to zero.

There’s another reason for the Laffer curve to stall above zero: the bleed from the official market to the black market goes BOTH ways.  A person might make something for his own consumption or for the black market, and that product can relieve the need for something in the open market – but leave the opportunity to buy something else on the open market instead.

In numerical terms, the original Laffer curve would require a behavior drag that would shift the maximum “robotic” (i.e. behavior neutral) curve peak from 35% to 24%.


Turns out humans worked just as hard at 94% tax rates as they did at 35% rates.  They lost productive capacity, but they did not intentionally avoid work.

Taxes become the backdrop against which we work.  We don’t work for the government’s benefit: we work for our own benefit and will try to make the best life we can no matter how ridiculous the government becomes.

In terms of taxes, there is NO DIFFERENCE between humans and robots.  Therefore, NEITHER should ever be taxed more than 35%.

That goes for “entities” like corporations, too.  The total effect of Federal, State, and Local taxes should NEVER exceed 35% in the American economy.

Now, the “Affordable Care Act” does throw a monkey wrench into the equation, though.  Is it a tax or not?  Regardless of the rhetoric, what is it really?

Truth is, I have no idea.  It’s a mandate to buy health insurance, but not an effective one.  It will certainly create a bureaucratic drag, but no one knows by how much.  Everything outside of that bureaucratic drag SHOULD be a wash in the tax equation.

So, I’ll conclude with this:

A PROPOSAL
 
1) Freeze all Federal taxes but one – the income tax
2) Freeze all State taxes but one – (let each state pick what they want)
3) Allow the unfrozen tax to float based on actual revenue data (see below)

Here’s how you float that last tax – MEASURE the inflation adjusted per capita revenues as I’ve done in this series of posts.  Set the rate at the historical peak.  If 35% begins to underperform, the graph will AUTOMATICALLY shift to either 34% or 36%.  If one of those underperforms it will continue to shift.

The shift will be slow, but based on empirical evidence.  There will be no sudden shocks, and everyone will know that the government is trying to maximize revenues (at least until we pay off the 16 trillion debt).

The rate will simply and automatically gravitate to WHATEVER WORKS BEST.  And if some other bogus tax / non-tax like Obamacare is thrown in, the measures will self-adjust in a short period of time.

Liberals think they’ll get more money at higher rates.

Conservatives think they’ll get more money at lower rates.

Let them BOTH put their money where their mouth is and agree to this automated optimizing proposal and get to the real world task they really need to do next: find a way to SPEND LESS than they take in.

Tim

 

 

 

Wednesday, January 23, 2013

01/23/2013 Civil War -- first shot cuts states by 20%


So far we’ve been looking at the effect of Federal tax rates on Federal revenues.

For some people it’s a hard sell – even if you give them all the source data and invite them to figure out a way it doesn’t fall as I’ve demonstrated.

Now for something simpler: the states.

If the Federal government raises rates, what happens to STATE revenues?

It’s not pretty:




The true size of government isn’t measured by how much of your life it can control, but in how many real dollars it can raise.

By reaching too far, our government will starve itself and the states from the very power it is trying to seize.

The states will respond by raising their own rates in a tax war with only one target: us.

The red line is a clearer picture of the economy as well, since it shows the raw effect of the Federal power grab.

Some states COULD, in theory, just ride it out.  But as Nate Silver commented recently, states have their own unfunded liability problem, with pensions growing in size faster than the working population.  On the total government spending chart Nate provides, we have now passed the critical threshold of 35% GNP.

It’s mathematically impossible for a government to grow after it passes 35% of GNP.  It can go all the way to 100% and it will get smaller in total wealth the entire way.

In theory, states can put up a good fight.  Federal spending has risen to 25% of GNP and the states to 15%.  That means that a state hike of 5% will only have the economic impact of a 3% hike for the Federal rates.

The bad news is that they have more to make up for.  The Federal rate hike from 35% to 43.8% was a 20% rate hike.  The states will get a 20% revenue cut.  To make that up they will try to raise state taxes by 20% at first, which will further depress their economies and revenue by an additional 4%, which means that states will not be able to stop until after they have raised rates by more than 25%.

But the worst news for the states is that their wealth is more mobile than wealth under Federal jurisdiction.  A person can leave one state for another without having to pay a penalty, and he won’t continue to be taxed like an American living abroad would be taxed on the Federal level.  The most vulnerable states – typically the “blue” states – will be far more damaged than less progressive “red” states.

The first cannon of a civil tax war has been fired.

It’s not over by a long shot.

And we’re all in the crosshairs.

Tim

 

 

Tuesday, January 22, 2013

01/22/2013 Milestone -- outperformance by more than 30%


Small Portfolio
XLU & IAU
19.73%
Sector
XLU
29.86%
Secular
IAU
9.59%
Large Portfolio
Date
Return
Days
RIMM
7/16/2012
146.90%
190
SEAC
9/25/2012
31.21%
119
CAJ
9/25/2012
5.73%
119
DDAIF
9/25/2012
10.52%
119
CFI
10/31/2012
41.84%
83
RE
11/26/2012
9.42%
57
CGX
12/12/2012
10.06%
41
OKE
12/28/2012
11.81%
25
HTSI
1/14/2013
6.91%
8
STRA
1/22/2013
-0.40%
0
S&P
Annualized
6.51%
Small Portfolio
Annualized
11.54%
Sector Model
Annualized
17.18%
Large Portfolio
Annualized
37.52%
S&P
Total
10.95%
Small Portfolio
Total
19.73%
Sector Model
Total
29.86%
Large Portfolio
Total
69.05%
Small Portfolio
Advantage
5.03%
Sector Model
Advantage
10.67%
Large Portfolio
Advantage
31.01%

 

Milestone.  May not last, but as of today the annualized return rate on the Mousetrap is outperforming the S&P 500 index by over 30%.

 

 

01/22/2013 State Source Data


In Constant (FY2005 Dollars)
Addendum:
Fiscal Year
Federal Max Tax Rate
State Tax Receipts
Composite Deflator
State Deflated
Population
State per capita receipts
1950
91.0%
7.9
0.1064
75
152.27
0.5
1951
91.0%
8.9
0.1047
85
154.88
0.6
1952
92.0%
9.9
0.1041
95
157.55
0.6
1953
92.0%
10.6
0.1124
94
160.18
0.6
1954
91.0%
11.1
0.1163
95
163.03
0.6
1955
91.0%
11.6
0.1203
96
165.93
0.6
1956
91.0%
13.4
0.1263
106
168.90
0.6
1957
91.0%
14.5
0.1327
110
171.98
0.6
1958
91.0%
14.9
0.1405
106
174.88
0.6
1959
91.0%
15.8
0.1460
109
177.83
0.6
1960
91.0%
18.0
0.1466
123
180.67
0.7
1961
91.0%
19.1
0.1507
126
183.69
0.7
1962
91.0%
20.6
0.1511
136
186.54
0.7
1963
77.0%
22.1
0.1579
140
189.24
0.7
1964
70.0%
24.2
0.1599
152
191.89
0.8
1965
70.0%
26.1
0.1620
161
194.30
0.8
1966
70.0%
29.4
0.1658
177
196.56
0.9
1967
70.0%
31.9
0.1700
188
198.71
0.9
1968
70.0%
36.4
0.1765
206
200.71
1.0
1969
70.0%
41.9
0.1881
223
202.68
1.1
1970
70.0%
48.0
0.1991
241
205.05
1.2
1971
70.0%
51.5
0.2133
242
207.66
1.2
1972
70.0%
59.9
0.2283
262
209.90
1.2
1973
70.0%
68.1
0.2412
282
211.91
1.3
1974
70.0%
74.2
0.2621
283
213.85
1.3
1975
70.0%
80.2
0.2889
277
215.97
1.3
1976
70.0%
89.3
0.3117
286
218.03
1.3
1977
70.0%
101.1
0.3371
300
222.59
1.3
1978
70.0%
113.3
0.3588
316
225.06
1.4
1979
70.0%
124.9
0.3902
320
227.22
1.4
1980
70.0%
137.1
0.4318
317
229.47
1.4
1981
50.0%
149.7
0.4789
313
231.66
1.3
1982
50.0%
162.6
0.5136
317
233.79
1.4
1983
50.0%
171.4
0.5393
318
235.82
1.3
1984
50.0%
196.8
0.5675
347
237.92
1.5
1985
50.0%
215.9
0.5868
368
240.13
1.5
1986
50.0%
228.1
0.6020
379
242.29
1.6
1987
38.5%
246.5
0.6210
397
244.50
1.6
1988
28.0%
264.1
0.6398
413
246.82
1.7
1989
28.0%
284.4
0.6634
429
249.62
1.7
1990
28.0%
300.5
0.6840
439
252.98
1.7
1991
31.0%
310.6
0.7162
434
256.51
1.7
1992
31.0%
331.2
0.7436
445
259.92
1.7
1993
39.6%
353.8
0.7637
463
263.13
1.8
1994
39.6%
373.3
0.7780
480
266.28
1.8
1995
39.6%
399.1
0.7992
499
269.39
1.9
1996
39.6%
418.4
0.8184
511
272.65
1.9
1997
39.6%
444.2
0.8356
532
275.85
1.9
1998
39.6%
473.1
0.8436
561
279.04
2.0
1999
39.6%
499.9
0.8554
584
282.16
2.1
2000
39.6%
539.7
0.8767
616
284.97
2.2
2001
39.1%
559.7
0.8988
623
287.62
2.2
2002
38.6%
535.2
0.9135
586
290.11
2.0
2003
35.0%
549.0
0.9375
586
292.81
2.0
2004
35.0%
591.8
0.9644
614
295.52
2.1
2005
35.0%
650.6
1.0000
651
298.38
2.2
2006
35.0%
716.0
1.0356
691
301.23
2.3
2007
35.0%
757.5
1.0638
712
304.09
2.3
2008
35.0%
779.7
1.1031
707
306.77
2.3
2009
35.0%
714.0
1.1085
644
309.33
2.1
2010
35.0%
701.6
1.1218
625
311.59
2.0
2011
35.0%
757.3
1.1525
657
313.85
2.1

 

Sources:

 

United States Population


 

2005 CPI deflator


 

Maximum Tax Rate by Year


 

Total US State by State Tax Receipts



See also the comparable Federal data from 1940-2011:
http://market-mousetrap.blogspot.com/2013/01/01152013-source-data_2926.html  

 
I have used the deflator used in the Federal data to list the State receipts in 2005 dollars.

The only added column is the receipts per capita, which is the receipts in 2005 dollars divided by the population.